You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
for some **stochastic discount factor** $m_{t+1}$.
136
139
137
-
The fixed discount factor $\beta$ in {eq}`rnapex` has been replaced by the random variable $m_{t+1}$.
140
+
Here the fixed discount factor $\beta$ in {eq}`rnapex` has been replaced by the random variable $m_{t+1}$.
138
141
139
-
The way anticipated future payoffs are evaluated can now depend on various random outcomes.
142
+
How anticipated future payoffs are evaluated now depends on statistical properties of $m_{t+1}$.
140
143
141
-
One example of this idea is that assets that tend to have good payoffs in bad states of the world might be regarded as more valuable.
144
+
The stochastic discount factor can be specified to capture the idea that assets that tend to have good payoffs in bad states of the world are valued more highly than other assets whose payoffs don't behave that way.
142
145
143
-
This is because they pay well when funds are more urgently wanted.
146
+
This is because such assets pay well when funds are more urgently wanted.
144
147
145
148
We give examples of how the stochastic discount factor has been modeled below.
146
149
@@ -200,11 +203,11 @@ The answer to this question depends on
200
203
201
204
For now we'll study the risk-neutral case in which the stochastic discount factor is constant.
202
205
203
-
We'll focus on how the asset prices depends on the dividend process.
206
+
We'll focus on how an asset price depends on a dividend process.
204
207
205
208
### Example 1: Constant Dividends
206
209
207
-
The simplest case is risk-neutral pricing in the face of a constant, non-random dividend stream $d_t = d > 0$.
210
+
The simplest case is risk-neutral price of a constant, non-random dividend stream $d_t = d > 0$.
208
211
209
212
Removing the expectation from {eq}`rnapex` and iterating forward gives
210
213
@@ -220,26 +223,26 @@ $$
220
223
\end{aligned}
221
224
$$
222
225
223
-
Unless prices explode in the future, this sequence converges to
226
+
If $\lim_{k \rightarrow + \infty} \beta^{k-1} p_{t+k} = 0$, this sequence converges to
224
227
225
228
```{math}
226
229
:label: ddet
227
230
228
231
\bar p := \frac{\beta d}{1-\beta}
229
232
```
230
233
231
-
This price is the equilibrium price in the constant dividend case.
234
+
This is the equilibrium price in the constant dividend case.
232
235
233
236
Indeed, simple algebra shows that setting $p_t = \bar p$ for all $t$
234
-
satisfies the equilibrium condition $p_t = \beta (d + p_{t+1})$.
237
+
satisfies the difference equation $p_t = \beta (d + p_{t+1})$.
235
238
236
239
### Example 2: Dividends with Deterministic Growth Paths
237
240
238
241
Consider a growing, non-random dividend process $d_{t+1} = g d_t$
239
242
where $0 < g \beta < 1$.
240
243
241
-
While prices are not usually constant when dividends grow over time, the price
242
-
dividend-ratio might be.
244
+
While prices are not usually constant when dividends grow over time, a price
245
+
dividend-ratio can be.
243
246
244
247
If we guess this, substituting $v_t = v$ into {eq}`pdex` as well as our
245
248
other assumptions, we get $v = \beta g (1 + v)$.
@@ -292,7 +295,7 @@ where
292
295
\qquad (x, y \in S)
293
296
$$
294
297
295
-
1. $g$ is a given function on $S$ taking positive values
298
+
1. $g$ is a given function on $S$ taking nonnegative values
296
299
297
300
You can think of
298
301
@@ -328,15 +331,15 @@ plt.tight_layout()
328
331
plt.show()
329
332
```
330
333
331
-
#### Pricing
334
+
#### Pricing Formula
332
335
333
336
To obtain asset prices in this setting, let's adapt our analysis from the case of deterministic growth.
334
337
335
338
In that case, we found that $v$ is constant.
336
339
337
-
This encourages us to guess that, in the current case, $v_t$ is constant given the state $X_t$.
340
+
This encourages us to guess that, in the current case, $v_t$ is a fixed function of the state $X_t$.
338
341
339
-
In other words, we are looking for a fixed function $v$ such that the price-dividend ratio satisfies $v_t = v(X_t)$.
342
+
We seek a function $v$ such that the price-dividend ratio satisfies $v_t = v(X_t)$.
340
343
341
344
We can substitute this guess into {eq}`pdex` to get
342
345
@@ -376,11 +379,11 @@ Here
376
379
* $K$ is the matrix $(K(x_i, x_j))_{1 \leq i, j \leq n}$.
377
380
* ${\mathbb 1}$ is a column vector of ones.
378
381
379
-
When does {eq}`vcumrn` have a unique solution?
382
+
When does equation {eq}`vcumrn` have a unique solution?
380
383
381
-
From the {ref}`Neumann series lemma <la_neumann>` and Gelfand's formula, this will be the case if $\beta K$ has spectral radius strictly less than one.
384
+
From the {ref}`Neumann series lemma <la_neumann>` and Gelfand's formula, equation {eq}`vcumrn` has a unique solution when $\beta K$ has spectral radius strictly less than one.
382
385
383
-
In other words, we require that the eigenvalues of $K$ be strictly less than $\beta^{-1}$ in modulus.
386
+
Thus, we require that the eigenvalues of $K$ be strictly less than $\beta^{-1}$ in modulus.
384
387
385
388
The solution is then
386
389
@@ -392,7 +395,7 @@ v = (I - \beta K)^{-1} \beta K{\mathbb 1}
392
395
393
396
### Code
394
397
395
-
Let's calculate and plot the price-dividend ratio at a set of parameters.
398
+
Let's calculate and plot the price-dividend ratio at some parameters.
396
399
397
400
As before, we'll generate $\{X_t\}$ as a {ref}`discretized AR1 process <mc_ex3>` and set $g_t = \exp(X_t)$.
398
401
@@ -494,7 +497,7 @@ v(X_t)
494
497
\left[
495
498
g(X_{t+1})^{1-\gamma} (1 + v(X_{t+1}) )
496
499
\right]
497
-
$$
500
+
$$ (eq:neweqn101)
498
501
499
502
Conditioning on $X_t = x$, we can write this as
500
503
@@ -509,7 +512,7 @@ $$
509
512
J(x, y) := g(y)^{1-\gamma} P(x, y)
510
513
$$
511
514
512
-
then we can rewrite in vector form as
515
+
then we can rewrite equation {eq}`eq:neweqn101} in vector form as
513
516
514
517
$$
515
518
v = \beta J ({\mathbb 1} + v )
@@ -523,7 +526,7 @@ Assuming that the spectral radius of $J$ is strictly less than $\beta^{-1}$, thi
523
526
v = (I - \beta J)^{-1} \beta J {\mathbb 1}
524
527
```
525
528
526
-
We will define a function tree_price to solve for $v$ given parameters stored in
529
+
We will define a function tree_price to compute $v$ given parameters stored in
527
530
the class AssetPriceModel
528
531
529
532
```{code-cell} python3
@@ -622,9 +625,9 @@ plt.show()
622
625
623
626
Notice that $v$ is decreasing in each case.
624
627
625
-
This is because, with a positively correlated state process, higher states suggest higher future consumption growth.
628
+
This is because, with a positively correlated state process, higher states indicate higher future consumption growth.
626
629
627
-
In the stochastic discount factor {eq}`lucsdf2`, higher growth decreases the
630
+
With the stochastic discount factor {eq}`lucsdf2`, higher growth decreases the
628
631
discount factor, lowering the weight placed on future returns.
629
632
630
633
#### Special Cases
@@ -654,7 +657,7 @@ A risk-free consol promises to pay a constant amount $\zeta> 0$ each period.
654
657
655
658
Recycling notation, let $p_t$ now be the price of an ex-coupon claim to the consol.
656
659
657
-
An ex-coupon claim to the consol entitles the owner at the end of period $t$ to
660
+
An ex-coupon claim to the consol entitles an owner at the end of period $t$ to
658
661
659
662
* $\zeta$ in period $t+1$, plus
660
663
* the right to sell the claim for $p_{t+1}$ next period
0 commit comments