You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/harrison_kreps.md
+33-32Lines changed: 33 additions & 32 deletions
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -82,7 +82,6 @@ There is a fixed number $A$ of shares of an asset.
82
82
83
83
Each share entitles its owner to a stream of dividends $\{d_t\}$ governed by a Markov chain defined on a state space $S \in \{0, 1\}$.
84
84
85
-
Thus, the stock is traded **ex dividend**.
86
85
87
86
The dividend obeys
88
87
@@ -94,9 +93,11 @@ d_t =
94
93
\end{cases}
95
94
$$
96
95
97
-
The owner of a share at the beginning of time $t$ is entitled to the dividend paid at time $t$.
96
+
An owner of a share at the end of time $t$ and the beginning of time $t+1$ is entitled to the dividend paid at time $t+1$.
97
+
98
+
Thus, the stock is traded **ex dividend**.
98
99
99
-
The owner of the share at the beginning of time $t$ is also entitled to sell the share to another investor during time $t$.
100
+
An owner of a share at the beginning of time $t+1$ is also entitled to sell the share to another investor during time $t+1$.
100
101
101
102
Two types $h=a, b$ of investors differ only in their beliefs about a Markov transition matrix $P$ with typical element
102
103
@@ -154,7 +155,7 @@ An owner of the asset at the end of time $t$ is entitled to the dividend at time
154
155
155
156
Both types of investors are risk-neutral and both have the same fixed discount factor $\beta \in (0,1)$.
156
157
157
-
In our numerical example, we’ll set $\beta = .75$, just as Harrison and Kreps did.
158
+
In our numerical example, we’ll set $\beta = .75$, just as Harrison and Kreps {cite}`HarrKreps1978`did.
158
159
159
160
We’ll eventually study the consequences of two alternative assumptions about the number of shares $A$ relative to the resources that our two types of investors can invest in the stock.
160
161
@@ -169,7 +170,7 @@ In case 2, both types of investors always hold at least some of the asset.
169
170
170
171
No short sales are allowed.
171
172
172
-
This matters because it limits how pessimists can express their opinion.
173
+
This matters because it limits how pessimists can express their opinions.
173
174
174
175
* They **can** express themselves by selling their shares.
175
176
* They **cannot** express themsevles more loudly by artificially "manufacturing shares" -- that is, they cannot borrow shares from more optimistic investors and then immediately sell them.
@@ -181,9 +182,9 @@ The above specifications of the perceived transition matrices $P_a$ and $P_b$, t
181
182
Remember that state $1$ is the high dividend state.
182
183
183
184
* In state $0$, a type $a$ agent is more optimistic about next period's dividend than a type $b$ agent.
184
-
* In state $1$, a type $b$ agent is more optimistic about next period's dividend.
185
+
* In state $1$, a type $b$ agent is more optimistic about next period's dividend than a type $a$ agaub is.
185
186
186
-
However, the stationary distributions $\pi_a = \begin{bmatrix} .57 & .43 \end{bmatrix}$ and $\pi_b = \begin{bmatrix} .43 & .57 \end{bmatrix}$ tell us that a type $B$ person is more optimistic about the dividend process in the long run than is a type $A$ person.
187
+
However, the stationary distributions $\pi_a = \begin{bmatrix} .57 & .43 \end{bmatrix}$ and $\pi_b = \begin{bmatrix} .43 & .57 \end{bmatrix}$ tell us that a type $b$ person is more optimistic about the dividend process in the long run than is a type $a$ person.
187
188
188
189
### Information
189
190
@@ -216,14 +217,14 @@ The table reports implications of Harrison and Kreps's specifications of $P_a,
216
217
```{raw} html
217
218
<div class="content-table"></div>
218
219
```
219
-
|$ s_t $|0|1|
220
-
|:---------------------:|:----:|:----:|
221
-
|$ p_a $|1.33|1.22|
222
-
|$ p_b $|1.45|1.91|
223
-
|$ p_o $|1.85|2.08|
224
-
|$ p_p $|1|1|
225
-
|$ \hat{p}_a $|1.85|1.69|
226
-
|$ \hat{p}_b $|1.69|2.08|
220
+
|$ s_t $| 0 | 1 |
221
+
|:-----------: |:---: |:---: |
222
+
|$ p_a $|1.33|1.22|
223
+
|$ p_b $|1.45|1.91|
224
+
|$ p_o $|1.85|2.08|
225
+
|$ p_p $| 1 | 1 |
226
+
|$ \hat{p}_a $|1.85|1.69|
227
+
|$ \hat{p}_b $|1.69|2.08|
227
228
228
229
Here
229
230
@@ -256,7 +257,7 @@ The price today equals the expected discounted value of tomorrow's dividend and
These equilibrium prices under homogeneous beliefs are important benchmarks for the subsequent analysis.
291
292
292
-
* $p_h(s)$ tells what investor $h$ thinks is the "fundamental value" of the asset.
293
+
* $p_h(s)$ tells what a type $h$ investor thinks is the "fundamental value" of the asset.
293
294
* Here "fundamental value" means the expected discounted present value of future dividends.
294
295
295
296
We will compare these fundamental values of the asset with equilibrium values when traders have different beliefs.
@@ -317,7 +318,7 @@ In this case, the marginal investor who prices the asset is the more optimistic
317
318
318
319
for $s=0,1$.
319
320
320
-
In the above equation, the $max$ on the right side is evidently over two prospective values of next period's payout
321
+
In the above equation, the $max$ on the right side is over the two prospective values of next period's payout
321
322
from owning the asset.
322
323
323
324
The marginal investor who prices the asset in state $s$ is of type $a$ if
@@ -368,7 +369,7 @@ Nevertheless, the economy recurrently visits a state that makes each investor wa
368
369
purchase the asset for more than he believes its future dividends are
369
370
worth.
370
371
371
-
The reason that an investor is willing to pay more than what he believes is warranted by fundamental value of the prospective dividend stream is he expects to have the option to sell the asset later to another investor who will value the asset more highly than he will.
372
+
An investor is willing to pay more than what he believes is warranted by fundamental value of the prospective dividend stream because he expects to have the option later to sell the asset to another investor who will value the asset more highly than he will then.
372
373
373
374
* Investors of type $a$ are willing to pay the following price for the asset
374
375
@@ -396,7 +397,7 @@ Investors of type $a$ want to sell the asset in state $1$ while investors of typ
396
397
397
398
* The asset changes hands whenever the state changes from $0$ to $1$ or from $1$ to $0$.
398
399
* The valuations $\hat p_a(s)$ and $\hat p_b(s)$ are displayed in the fourth and fifth rows of the table.
399
-
* Even the pessimistic investors who don't buy the asset think that it is worth more than they think future dividends are worth.
400
+
* Even pessimistic investors who don't buy the asset think that it is worth more than they think future dividends are worth.
400
401
401
402
Here's code to solve for $\bar p$, $\hat p_a$ and $\hat p_b$ using the iterative method described above
Scheinkman stresses these features of the Harrison-Kreps model:
500
501
501
-
*Compared to the homogeneous beliefs setting leading to the pricing formula, high volume occurs when the Harrison-Kreps pricing formula prevails.
502
+
* High volume occurs when the Harrison-Kreps pricing formula {eq}`hakr2` prevails.
502
503
503
-
Type $a$ investors sell the entire stock of the asset to type $b$ investors every time the state switches from $s_t =0$ to $s_t =1$.
504
+
* Type $a$ investors sell the entire stock of the asset to type $b$ investors every time the state switches from $s_t =0$ to $s_t =1$.
504
505
505
-
Type $b$ investors sell the asset to type $a$ investors every time the state switches from $s_t = 1$ to $s_t =0$.
506
+
* Type $b$ investors sell the asset to type $a$ investors every time the state switches from $s_t = 1$ to $s_t =0$.
506
507
507
508
Scheinkman takes this as a strength of the model because he observes high volume during *famous bubbles*.
508
509
509
-
* If the *supply* of the asset is increased sufficiently either physically (more "houses" are built) or artificially (ways are invented to short sell "houses"), bubbles end when the supply has grown enough to outstrip optimistic investors’ resources for purchasing the asset.
510
+
* If the *supply* of the asset is increased sufficiently either physically (more "houses" are built) or artificially (ways are invented to short sell "houses"), bubbles end when the asset supply has grown enough to outstrip optimistic investors’ resources for purchasing the asset.
510
511
* If optimistic investors finance their purchases by borrowing, tightening leverage constraints can extinguish a bubble.
511
512
512
513
Scheinkman extracts insights about the effects of financial regulations on bubbles.
@@ -522,14 +523,14 @@ This exercise invites you to recreate the summary table using the functions we h
522
523
```{raw} html
523
524
<div class="content-table"></div>
524
525
```
525
-
|$s_t$|0|1|
526
-
|:---------------------:|:----:|:----:|
527
-
|$p_a$|1.33|1.22|
528
-
|$p_b$|1.45|1.91|
529
-
|$p_o$|1.85|2.08|
530
-
|$p_p$|1|1|
531
-
|$\hat{p}_a$|1.85|1.69|
532
-
|$\hat{p}_b$|1.69|2.08|
526
+
|$s_t$ | 0 | 1 |
527
+
|:---------: | :---: | :---: |
528
+
|$p_a$ | 1.33 | 1.22|
529
+
|$p_b$ | 1.45 | 1.91|
530
+
|$p_o$ | 1.85 | 2.08|
531
+
|$p_p$ | 1 | 1 |
532
+
|$\hat{p}_a$ | 1.85 | 1.69|
533
+
|$\hat{p}_b$ | 1.69 | 2.08|
533
534
534
535
You will want first to define the transition matrices and dividend payoff vector.
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/hoist_failure.md
+2-1Lines changed: 2 additions & 1 deletion
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -504,7 +504,8 @@ Probabilities for each event are recorded as failure rates per year.
504
504
505
505
## Failure Rates Unknown
506
506
507
-
Now we come to the problem that really interests us, following {cite}`Ardron_2018` and Greenfield and Sargent {cite}`Greenfield_Sargent_1993` in the spirit of Apostolakis {cite}`apostolakis1990`.
507
+
Now we come to the problem that really interests us, following {cite}`Ardron_2018` and Greenfield and Sargent
508
+
{cite}`Greenfield_Sargent_1993` in the spirit of Apostolakis {cite}`apostolakis1990`.
508
509
509
510
The constituent probabilities or failure rates $P(A_i)$ are not known a priori and have to be estimated.
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/house_auction.md
+2-2Lines changed: 2 additions & 2 deletions
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -34,7 +34,7 @@ We describe two distinct mechanisms
34
34
35
35
* A multiple rounds, ascending bid auction
36
36
37
-
* A special case of a Groves-Clarke ({cite}`Groves_73`, {cite}`Clarke_71`) mechanism with a benevolent social planner
37
+
* A special case of a Groves-Clarke {cite}`Groves_73`, {cite}`Clarke_71` mechanism with a benevolent social planner
38
38
39
39
40
40
**Note:** In 1994, the multiple rounds, ascending bid auction was actually used by Stanford University to sell leases to 9 lots on the Stanford campus to eligible faculty members.
@@ -1019,7 +1019,7 @@ We now decribe an alternative way for society to allocate $n$ houses to $m$ pos
1019
1019
1020
1020
We continue to assume that each buyer can purchase at most one house.
1021
1021
1022
-
The mechanism is a very special case of a Groves-Clarke mechanism({cite}`Groves_73`, {cite}`Clarke_71`).
1022
+
The mechanism is a very special case of a Groves-Clarke mechanism{cite}`Groves_73`, {cite}`Clarke_71`.
1023
1023
1024
1024
Its special structure substantially simplifies writing Python code to find an optimal allocation.
0 commit comments