Skip to content

Commit d6642a2

Browse files
Tom's latest edits of five new lectures
1 parent fd271c0 commit d6642a2

File tree

5 files changed

+39
-37
lines changed

5 files changed

+39
-37
lines changed

lectures/eig_circulant.md

Lines changed: 1 addition & 1 deletion
Original file line numberDiff line numberDiff line change
@@ -474,7 +474,7 @@ x[0:2] = 1/2
474474
x
475475
```
476476
477-
Apply a discrete fourier transform.
477+
Apply a discrete Fourier transform.
478478
479479
```{code-cell} ipython3
480480
X = DFT(x)

lectures/harrison_kreps.md

Lines changed: 33 additions & 32 deletions
Original file line numberDiff line numberDiff line change
@@ -82,7 +82,6 @@ There is a fixed number $A$ of shares of an asset.
8282

8383
Each share entitles its owner to a stream of dividends $\{d_t\}$ governed by a Markov chain defined on a state space $S \in \{0, 1\}$.
8484

85-
Thus, the stock is traded **ex dividend**.
8685

8786
The dividend obeys
8887

@@ -94,9 +93,11 @@ d_t =
9493
\end{cases}
9594
$$
9695

97-
The owner of a share at the beginning of time $t$ is entitled to the dividend paid at time $t$.
96+
An owner of a share at the end of time $t$ and the beginning of time $t+1$ is entitled to the dividend paid at time $t+1$.
97+
98+
Thus, the stock is traded **ex dividend**.
9899

99-
The owner of the share at the beginning of time $t$ is also entitled to sell the share to another investor during time $t$.
100+
An owner of a share at the beginning of time $t+1$ is also entitled to sell the share to another investor during time $t+1$.
100101

101102
Two types $h=a, b$ of investors differ only in their beliefs about a Markov transition matrix $P$ with typical element
102103

@@ -154,7 +155,7 @@ An owner of the asset at the end of time $t$ is entitled to the dividend at time
154155

155156
Both types of investors are risk-neutral and both have the same fixed discount factor $\beta \in (0,1)$.
156157

157-
In our numerical example, we’ll set $\beta = .75$, just as Harrison and Kreps did.
158+
In our numerical example, we’ll set $\beta = .75$, just as Harrison and Kreps {cite}`HarrKreps1978` did.
158159

159160
We’ll eventually study the consequences of two alternative assumptions about the number of shares $A$ relative to the resources that our two types of investors can invest in the stock.
160161

@@ -169,7 +170,7 @@ In case 2, both types of investors always hold at least some of the asset.
169170

170171
No short sales are allowed.
171172

172-
This matters because it limits how pessimists can express their opinion.
173+
This matters because it limits how pessimists can express their opinions.
173174

174175
* They **can** express themselves by selling their shares.
175176
* They **cannot** express themsevles more loudly by artificially "manufacturing shares" -- that is, they cannot borrow shares from more optimistic investors and then immediately sell them.
@@ -181,9 +182,9 @@ The above specifications of the perceived transition matrices $P_a$ and $P_b$, t
181182
Remember that state $1$ is the high dividend state.
182183

183184
* In state $0$, a type $a$ agent is more optimistic about next period's dividend than a type $b$ agent.
184-
* In state $1$, a type $b$ agent is more optimistic about next period's dividend.
185+
* In state $1$, a type $b$ agent is more optimistic about next period's dividend than a type $a$ agaub is.
185186

186-
However, the stationary distributions $\pi_a = \begin{bmatrix} .57 & .43 \end{bmatrix}$ and $\pi_b = \begin{bmatrix} .43 & .57 \end{bmatrix}$ tell us that a type $B$ person is more optimistic about the dividend process in the long run than is a type $A$ person.
187+
However, the stationary distributions $\pi_a = \begin{bmatrix} .57 & .43 \end{bmatrix}$ and $\pi_b = \begin{bmatrix} .43 & .57 \end{bmatrix}$ tell us that a type $b$ person is more optimistic about the dividend process in the long run than is a type $a$ person.
187188

188189
### Information
189190

@@ -216,14 +217,14 @@ The table reports implications of Harrison and Kreps's specifications of $P_a,
216217
```{raw} html
217218
<div class="content-table"></div>
218219
```
219-
|$ s_t $|0|1|
220-
|:---------------------:|:----:|:----:|
221-
|$ p_a $|1.33|1.22|
222-
|$ p_b $|1.45|1.91|
223-
|$ p_o $|1.85|2.08|
224-
|$ p_p $|1|1|
225-
|$ \hat{p}_a $|1.85|1.69|
226-
|$ \hat{p}_b $|1.69|2.08|
220+
| $ s_t $ | 0 | 1 |
221+
| :-----------: | :---: | :---: |
222+
| $ p_a $ | 1.33 | 1.22 |
223+
| $ p_b $ | 1.45 | 1.91 |
224+
| $ p_o $ | 1.85 | 2.08 |
225+
| $ p_p $ | 1 | 1 |
226+
| $ \hat{p}_a $ | 1.85 | 1.69 |
227+
| $ \hat{p}_b $ | 1.69 | 2.08 |
227228

228229
Here
229230

@@ -256,7 +257,7 @@ The price today equals the expected discounted value of tomorrow's dividend and
256257

257258
$$
258259
p_h(s) = \beta \left( P_h(s,0) (0 + p_h(0)) + P_h(s,1) ( 1 + p_h(1)) \right), \quad s = 0, 1
259-
$$
260+
$$ (eq:assetpricehomog)
260261
261262
These equations imply that the equilibrium price vector is
262263
@@ -289,7 +290,7 @@ def price_single_beliefs(transition, dividend_payoff, β=.75):
289290
290291
These equilibrium prices under homogeneous beliefs are important benchmarks for the subsequent analysis.
291292
292-
* $p_h(s)$ tells what investor $h$ thinks is the "fundamental value" of the asset.
293+
* $p_h(s)$ tells what a type $h$ investor thinks is the "fundamental value" of the asset.
293294
* Here "fundamental value" means the expected discounted present value of future dividends.
294295
295296
We will compare these fundamental values of the asset with equilibrium values when traders have different beliefs.
@@ -317,7 +318,7 @@ In this case, the marginal investor who prices the asset is the more optimistic
317318
318319
for $s=0,1$.
319320
320-
In the above equation, the $max$ on the right side is evidently over two prospective values of next period's payout
321+
In the above equation, the $max$ on the right side is over the two prospective values of next period's payout
321322
from owning the asset.
322323
323324
The marginal investor who prices the asset in state $s$ is of type $a$ if
@@ -368,7 +369,7 @@ Nevertheless, the economy recurrently visits a state that makes each investor wa
368369
purchase the asset for more than he believes its future dividends are
369370
worth.
370371
371-
The reason that an investor is willing to pay more than what he believes is warranted by fundamental value of the prospective dividend stream is he expects to have the option to sell the asset later to another investor who will value the asset more highly than he will.
372+
An investor is willing to pay more than what he believes is warranted by fundamental value of the prospective dividend stream because he expects to have the option later to sell the asset to another investor who will value the asset more highly than he will then.
372373
373374
* Investors of type $a$ are willing to pay the following price for the asset
374375
@@ -396,7 +397,7 @@ Investors of type $a$ want to sell the asset in state $1$ while investors of typ
396397
397398
* The asset changes hands whenever the state changes from $0$ to $1$ or from $1$ to $0$.
398399
* The valuations $\hat p_a(s)$ and $\hat p_b(s)$ are displayed in the fourth and fifth rows of the table.
399-
* Even the pessimistic investors who don't buy the asset think that it is worth more than they think future dividends are worth.
400+
* Even pessimistic investors who don't buy the asset think that it is worth more than they think future dividends are worth.
400401
401402
Here's code to solve for $\bar p$, $\hat p_a$ and $\hat p_b$ using the iterative method described above
402403
@@ -498,15 +499,15 @@ def price_pessimistic_beliefs(transitions, dividend_payoff, β=.75,
498499
499500
Scheinkman stresses these features of the Harrison-Kreps model:
500501
501-
* Compared to the homogeneous beliefs setting leading to the pricing formula, high volume occurs when the Harrison-Kreps pricing formula prevails.
502+
* High volume occurs when the Harrison-Kreps pricing formula {eq}`hakr2` prevails.
502503
503-
Type $a$ investors sell the entire stock of the asset to type $b$ investors every time the state switches from $s_t =0$ to $s_t =1$.
504+
* Type $a$ investors sell the entire stock of the asset to type $b$ investors every time the state switches from $s_t =0$ to $s_t =1$.
504505
505-
Type $b$ investors sell the asset to type $a$ investors every time the state switches from $s_t = 1$ to $s_t =0$.
506+
* Type $b$ investors sell the asset to type $a$ investors every time the state switches from $s_t = 1$ to $s_t =0$.
506507
507508
Scheinkman takes this as a strength of the model because he observes high volume during *famous bubbles*.
508509
509-
* If the *supply* of the asset is increased sufficiently either physically (more "houses" are built) or artificially (ways are invented to short sell "houses"), bubbles end when the supply has grown enough to outstrip optimistic investors’ resources for purchasing the asset.
510+
* If the *supply* of the asset is increased sufficiently either physically (more "houses" are built) or artificially (ways are invented to short sell "houses"), bubbles end when the asset supply has grown enough to outstrip optimistic investors’ resources for purchasing the asset.
510511
* If optimistic investors finance their purchases by borrowing, tightening leverage constraints can extinguish a bubble.
511512
512513
Scheinkman extracts insights about the effects of financial regulations on bubbles.
@@ -522,14 +523,14 @@ This exercise invites you to recreate the summary table using the functions we h
522523
```{raw} html
523524
<div class="content-table"></div>
524525
```
525-
|$s_t$|0|1|
526-
|:---------------------:|:----:|:----:|
527-
|$p_a$|1.33|1.22|
528-
|$p_b$|1.45|1.91|
529-
|$p_o$|1.85|2.08|
530-
|$p_p$|1|1|
531-
|$\hat{p}_a$|1.85|1.69|
532-
|$\hat{p}_b$|1.69|2.08|
526+
| $s_t$ | 0 | 1 |
527+
| :---------: | :---: | :---: |
528+
| $p_a$ | 1.33 | 1.22 |
529+
| $p_b$ | 1.45 | 1.91 |
530+
| $p_o$ | 1.85 | 2.08 |
531+
| $p_p$ | 1 | 1 |
532+
| $\hat{p}_a$ | 1.85 | 1.69 |
533+
| $\hat{p}_b$ | 1.69 | 2.08 |
533534
534535
You will want first to define the transition matrices and dividend payoff vector.
535536

lectures/hoist_failure.md

Lines changed: 2 additions & 1 deletion
Original file line numberDiff line numberDiff line change
@@ -504,7 +504,8 @@ Probabilities for each event are recorded as failure rates per year.
504504
505505
## Failure Rates Unknown
506506
507-
Now we come to the problem that really interests us, following {cite}`Ardron_2018` and Greenfield and Sargent {cite}`Greenfield_Sargent_1993` in the spirit of Apostolakis {cite}`apostolakis1990`.
507+
Now we come to the problem that really interests us, following {cite}`Ardron_2018` and Greenfield and Sargent
508+
{cite}`Greenfield_Sargent_1993` in the spirit of Apostolakis {cite}`apostolakis1990`.
508509
509510
The constituent probabilities or failure rates $P(A_i)$ are not known a priori and have to be estimated.
510511

lectures/house_auction.md

Lines changed: 2 additions & 2 deletions
Original file line numberDiff line numberDiff line change
@@ -34,7 +34,7 @@ We describe two distinct mechanisms
3434

3535
* A multiple rounds, ascending bid auction
3636

37-
* A special case of a Groves-Clarke ({cite}`Groves_73`, {cite}`Clarke_71`) mechanism with a benevolent social planner
37+
* A special case of a Groves-Clarke {cite}`Groves_73`, {cite}`Clarke_71` mechanism with a benevolent social planner
3838

3939

4040
**Note:** In 1994, the multiple rounds, ascending bid auction was actually used by Stanford University to sell leases to 9 lots on the Stanford campus to eligible faculty members.
@@ -1019,7 +1019,7 @@ We now decribe an alternative way for society to allocate $n$ houses to $m$ pos
10191019

10201020
We continue to assume that each buyer can purchase at most one house.
10211021

1022-
The mechanism is a very special case of a Groves-Clarke mechanism({cite}`Groves_73`, {cite}`Clarke_71`).
1022+
The mechanism is a very special case of a Groves-Clarke mechanism {cite}`Groves_73`, {cite}`Clarke_71`.
10231023

10241024
Its special structure substantially simplifies writing Python code to find an optimal allocation.
10251025

lectures/two_auctions.md

Lines changed: 1 addition & 1 deletion
Original file line numberDiff line numberDiff line change
@@ -11,7 +11,7 @@ kernelspec:
1111
name: python3
1212
---
1313

14-
# Two auctions
14+
# First-Price and Second-Price Auctions
1515

1616
In this lecture we'll learn about and simulate two classic auctions:
1717

0 commit comments

Comments
 (0)