Skip to content

Commit 74ed4bc

Browse files
authored
MIGRATE: [markov_asset] migrate lecture-source (5623ec6) with manual adjustment (#109)
* migrate lecture-source (5623ec6) with manual adjustment * apply updated bib file
1 parent 221dbfd commit 74ed4bc

File tree

2 files changed

+25
-19
lines changed

2 files changed

+25
-19
lines changed

lectures/_static/quant-econ.bib

Lines changed: 1 addition & 1 deletion
Original file line numberDiff line numberDiff line change
@@ -790,7 +790,7 @@ @article{HarrisonKreps1979
790790

791791
@article{HansenRichard1987,
792792
author={Hansen, Lars Peter and Richard, Scott F},
793-
title={{The Role of Conditioning Information in Deducing Testable}},
793+
title={The Role of Conditioning Information in Deducing Testable Restrictions Implied by Dynamc Asset Pricing Models},
794794
journal={Econometrica},
795795
year=1987,
796796
volume={55},

lectures/markov_asset.md

Lines changed: 24 additions & 18 deletions
Original file line numberDiff line numberDiff line change
@@ -140,7 +140,7 @@ The way anticipated future payoffs are evaluated can now depend on various rando
140140

141141
One example of this idea is that assets that tend to have good payoffs in bad states of the world might be regarded as more valuable.
142142

143-
This is because they pay well when the funds are more urgently needed.
143+
This is because they pay well when funds are more urgently wanted.
144144

145145
We give examples of how the stochastic discount factor has been modeled below.
146146

@@ -166,6 +166,8 @@ It is useful to regard equation {eq}`lteeqs102` as a generalization of equatio
166166

167167
* In equation {eq}`rnapex`, the stochastic discount factor $m_{t+1} = \beta$, a constant.
168168
* In equation {eq}`rnapex`, the covariance term ${\rm cov}_t (m_{t+1}, d_{t+1}+ p_{t+1})$ is zero because $m_{t+1} = \beta$.
169+
* In equation {eq}`rnapex`, ${\mathbb E}_t m_{t+1}$ can be interpreted as the reciprocal of the one-period risk-free gross interest rate.
170+
* When $m_{t+1}$ is covaries more negatively with the payout $p_{t+1} + d_{t+1}$, the price of the asset is lower.
169171

170172
Equation {eq}`lteeqs102` asserts that the covariance of the stochastic discount factor with the one period payout $d_{t+1} + p_{t+1}$ is an important determinant of the price $p_t$.
171173

@@ -196,7 +198,9 @@ The answer to this question depends on
196198
1. the process we specify for dividends
197199
1. the stochastic discount factor and how it correlates with dividends
198200

199-
For now let's focus on the risk-neutral case, where the stochastic discount factor is constant, and study how prices depend on the dividend process.
201+
For now we'll study the risk-neutral case in which the stochastic discount factor is constant.
202+
203+
We'll focus on how the asset prices depends on the dividend process.
200204

201205
### Example 1: Constant Dividends
202206

@@ -294,8 +298,8 @@ You can think of
294298

295299
* $S$ as $n$ possible "states of the world" and $X_t$ as the
296300
current state.
297-
* $g$ as a function that maps a given state $X_t$ into a growth
298-
factor $g_t = g(X_t)$ for the endowment.
301+
* $g$ as a function that maps a given state $X_t$ into a growth of dividends
302+
factor $g_t = g(X_t)$.
299303
* $\ln g_t = \ln (d_{t+1} / d_t)$ is the growth rate of dividends.
300304

301305
(For a refresher on notation and theory for finite Markov chains see {doc}`this lecture <finite_markov>`)
@@ -424,13 +428,13 @@ Moreover, dividend growth is increasing in the state.
424428

425429
The anticipation of high future dividend growth leads to a high price-dividend ratio.
426430

427-
## Asset Prices under Risk Aversion
431+
## Risk Aversion and Asset Prices
428432

429433
Now let's turn to the case where agents are risk averse.
430434

431435
We'll price several distinct assets, including
432436

433-
* The price of an endowment stream
437+
* An endowment stream
434438
* A consol (a type of bond issued by the UK government in the 19th century)
435439
* Call options on a consol
436440

@@ -453,7 +457,7 @@ where $u$ is a concave utility function and $c_t$ is time $t$ consumption of a r
453457

454458
(A derivation of this expression is given in a [later lecture](https://python-advanced.quantecon.org/lucas_model.html))
455459

456-
Assume the existence of an endowment that follows {eq}`mass_fmce`.
460+
Assume the existence of an endowment that follows growth process {eq}`mass_fmce`.
457461

458462
The asset being priced is a claim on the endowment process.
459463

@@ -725,26 +729,28 @@ def consol_price(ap, ζ):
725729

726730
### Pricing an Option to Purchase the Consol
727731

728-
Let's now price options of varying maturity that give the right to purchase a consol at a price $p_S$.
732+
Let's now price options of varying maturities.
733+
734+
We'll study an option that gives the owner the right to purchase a consol at a price $p_S$.
729735

730736
#### An Infinite Horizon Call Option
731737

732738
We want to price an infinite horizon option to purchase a consol at a price $p_S$.
733739

734-
The option entitles the owner at the beginning of a period either to
740+
The option entitles the owner at the beginning of a period either
735741

736-
1. purchase the bond at price $p_S$ now, or
737-
1. Not to exercise the option now but to retain the right to exercise it later
742+
1. to purchase the bond at price $p_S$ now, or
743+
1. not to exercise the option to purchase the asset now but to retain the right to exercise it later
738744

739745
Thus, the owner either *exercises* the option now or chooses *not to exercise* and wait until next period.
740746

741747
This is termed an infinite-horizon *call option* with *strike price* $p_S$.
742748

743-
The owner of the option is entitled to purchase the consol at the price $p_S$ at the beginning of any period, after the coupon has been paid to the previous owner of the bond.
749+
The owner of the option is entitled to purchase the consol at price $p_S$ at the beginning of any period, after the coupon has been paid to the previous owner of the bond.
744750

745751
The fundamentals of the economy are identical with the one above, including the stochastic discount factor and the process for consumption.
746752

747-
Let $w(X_t, p_S)$ be the value of the option when the time $t$ growth state is known to be $X_t$ but *before* the owner has decided whether or not to exercise the option
753+
Let $w(X_t, p_S)$ be the value of the option when the time $t$ growth state is known to be $X_t$ but *before* the owner has decided whether to exercise the option
748754
at time $t$ (i.e., today).
749755

750756
Recalling that $p(X_t)$ is the value of the consol when the initial growth state is $X_t$, the value of the option satisfies
@@ -789,7 +795,7 @@ T w
789795
= \max \{ \beta M w,\; p - p_S {\mathbb 1} \}
790796
$$
791797

792-
Start at some initial $w$ and iterate to convergence with $T$.
798+
Start at some initial $w$ and iterate with $T$ to convergence .
793799

794800
We can find the solution with the following function call_option
795801

@@ -858,12 +864,12 @@ ax.legend(loc='upper right')
858864
plt.show()
859865
```
860866

861-
In large states, the value of the option is close to zero.
867+
In high values of the Markov growth state, the value of the option is close to zero.
862868

863-
This is despite the fact the Markov chain is irreducible and low states ---
864-
where the consol prices are high --- will eventually be visited.
869+
This is despite the facts that the Markov chain is irreducible and that low states ---
870+
where the consol prices are high --- will be visited recurrently.
865871

866-
The reason is that $\beta=0.9$, so the future is discounted relatively rapidly.
872+
The reason for low valuations in high Markov growth states is that $\beta=0.9$, so future payoffs are discounted substantially.
867873

868874
### Risk-Free Rates
869875

0 commit comments

Comments
 (0)