You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
We can arrange {eq}`lake_model` as a linear system of equations in matrix form $x_{t+1} = Ax_t$ such that:
100
+
We can arrange {eq}`lake_model` as a linear system of equations in matrix form $x_{t+1} = Ax_t$ where
98
101
99
102
$$
100
103
x_{t+1} =
101
104
\begin{bmatrix}
102
105
u_{t+1} \\
103
106
e_{t+1}
104
107
\end{bmatrix}
105
-
, \; A =
108
+
\quad
109
+
A =
106
110
\begin{bmatrix}
107
111
(1-d)(1-\lambda) + b & \alpha(1-d) + b \\
108
112
(1-d)\lambda & (1 - \alpha)(1-d)
109
113
\end{bmatrix}
110
-
\; \text{and} \;
114
+
\quad \text{and} \quad
111
115
x_t =
112
116
\begin{bmatrix}
113
117
u_t \\
114
118
e_t
115
-
\end{bmatrix}
119
+
\end{bmatrix}.
116
120
$$
117
121
118
122
Suppose at $t=0$ we have $x_0 = \begin{bmatrix} u_0 & e_0 \end{bmatrix}^\top$.
@@ -127,6 +131,8 @@ What long-run unemployment rate and employment rate should we expect?
127
131
128
132
Do long-run outcomes depend on the initial values $(u_0, e_o)$?
129
133
134
+
### Visualising the Long-Run Outcomes
135
+
130
136
Let us first plot the time series of unemployment $u_t$, employment $e_t$, and labor force $n_t$.
131
137
132
138
```{code-cell} ipython3
@@ -219,7 +225,7 @@ plt.show()
219
225
220
226
Not surprisingly, we observe that labor force $n_t$ increases at a constant rate.
221
227
222
-
This conincides with the fact there is only one inflow source (new entrants pool) to unemployment and employment pools.
228
+
This coincides with the fact there is only one inflow source (new entrants pool) to unemployment and employment pools.
223
229
224
230
The inflow and outflow of labor market system
225
231
is determined by constant exit rate and entry rate of labor market in the long run.
@@ -229,14 +235,22 @@ In detail, let $\mathbb{1}=[1, 1]^\top$ be a vector of ones.
229
235
Observe that
230
236
231
237
$$
232
-
n_{t+1} = u_{t+1} + e_{t+1} = \mathbb{1}^\top x_t = \mathbb{1}^\top A x_t = (1 + b - d) (u_t + e_t) = (1 + b - d) n_t.
238
+
\begin{aligned}
239
+
n_{t+1} &= u_{t+1} + e_{t+1} \\
240
+
&= \mathbb{1}^\top x_{t+1} \\
241
+
&= \mathbb{1}^\top A x_t \\
242
+
&= (1 + b - d) (u_t + e_t) \\
243
+
&= (1 + b - d) n_t.
244
+
\end{aligned}
233
245
$$
234
246
235
247
Hence, the growth rate of $n_t$ is fixed at $1 + b - d$.
236
248
237
249
Moreover, the times series of unemployment and employment seems to grow at some stable rates in the long run.
238
250
239
-
Since by intuition if we consider unemployment pool and employment pool as a closed system, the growth should be similar the labor force.
251
+
### The Application of Perron-Frobenius Theorem
252
+
253
+
Since by intuition if we consider unemployment pool and employment pool as a closed system, the growth should be similar to the labor force.
240
254
241
255
We next ask whether the long run growth rates of $e_t$ and $u_t$
242
256
also dominated by $1+b-d$ as labor force.
@@ -253,6 +267,8 @@ $x_{t+1} = Ax_t$ or in short $x_t = A^tx_0$.
253
267
This theorem helps characterise the dominant eigenvalue $r(A)$ which
254
268
determines the behavior of this iterative process.
255
269
270
+
#### Dominant Eigenvector
271
+
256
272
We now illustrate the power of the Perron-Frobenius theorem by showing how it
257
273
helps us to analyze the lake model.
258
274
@@ -264,7 +280,7 @@ $$
264
280
r(A) := \max\{|\lambda|: \lambda \text{ is an eigenvalue of } A \}
265
281
$$
266
282
267
-
- any other eigenvalue $\lambda$ in absolue value is strictly smaller than $r(A)$: $|\lambda|< r(A)$,
283
+
- any other eigenvalue $\lambda$ in absolute value is strictly smaller than $r(A)$: $|\lambda|< r(A)$,
268
284
269
285
- there exist unique and everywhere positive right eigenvector $\phi$ (column vector) and left eigenvector $\psi$ (row vector):
270
286
@@ -278,7 +294,7 @@ $$
278
294
r(A)^{-t} A^t \to \phi \psi
279
295
$$
280
296
281
-
The last statement implies that the magnitude of $A^t$ is identical to the magnitude of $r(A)^t$ in the long run, where $r(A)$ can be considered as the dominated eigenvalue in this lecture.
297
+
The last statement implies that the magnitude of $A^t$ is identical to the magnitude of $r(A)^t$ in the long run, where $r(A)$ can be considered as the dominant eigenvalue in this lecture.
282
298
283
299
Therefore, the magnitude $x_t = A^t x_0$ is also dominated by $r(A)^t$ in the long run.
284
300
@@ -399,9 +415,11 @@ The graph illustrates that for two distinct initial conditions $x_0$ the sequenc
399
415
400
416
This suggests that all such sequences share strong similarities in the long run, determined by the dominant eigenvector $\bar{x}$.
401
417
418
+
#### Negative Growth Rate
419
+
402
420
In the example illustrated above we considered parameters such that overall growth rate of the labor force $g>0$.
403
421
404
-
Suppose now we are faced with a situation where the $g<0$, i.e, negative growth in the labor force.
422
+
Suppose now we are faced with a situation where the $g<0$, i.e., negative growth in the labor force.
405
423
406
424
This means that $b-d<0$, i.e., workers exit the market faster than they enter.
We see that the growth of $u_t$ and $e_t$ also dominated by $r(A) = 1+g$ in the long run: $x_t$ grows along $D$ as $r(A) > 1$ and converges to $(0, 0)$ as $r(A) < 1$.
443
467
444
-
Moreover, the long-run uneumploment and employment are steady fractions of $n_t$.
468
+
Moreover, the long-run unemployment and employment are steady fractions of $n_t$.
445
469
446
470
The latter implies that $\bar{u}$ and $\bar{e}$ are long-run unemployment rate and employment rate, respectively.
447
471
448
472
In detail, we have the unemployment rates and employment rates: $x_t / n_t = A^t n_0 / n_t \to \bar{x}$ as $t \to \infty$.
449
473
450
-
To illustate the dynamics of the rates, let $\hat{A} := A / (1+g)$ be the transition matrix of $r_t := x_t/ n_t$.
474
+
To illustrate the dynamics of the rates, let $\hat{A} := A / (1+g)$ be the transition matrix of $r_t := x_t/ n_t$.
451
475
452
476
The dynamics of the rates follow
453
477
@@ -461,7 +485,10 @@ Observe that the column sums of $\hat{A}$ are all one so that $r(\hat{A})=1$.
461
485
One can check that $\bar{x}$ is also the right eigenvector of $\hat{A}$ corresponding to $r(\hat{A})$ that $\bar{x} = \hat{A} \bar{x}$.
462
486
463
487
Moreover, $\hat{A}^t r_0 \to \bar{x}$ as $t \to \infty$ for any $r_0 = x_0 / n_0$, since the above discussion implies
0 commit comments