Skip to content

Commit 43fd5a3

Browse files
Tom's edits of three more lectures in intro repo
1 parent dfd749d commit 43fd5a3

File tree

3 files changed

+142
-108
lines changed

3 files changed

+142
-108
lines changed

lectures/cagan_ree.md

+19-16
Original file line numberDiff line numberDiff line change
@@ -13,23 +13,26 @@ kernelspec:
1313

1414
# A Monetarist Theory of Price Levels
1515

16-
## Introduction
16+
## Overview
1717

1818

1919
We'll use linear algebra first to explain and then do some experiments with a "monetarist theory of price levels".
2020

21-
Sometimes this theory is also called a "fiscal theory of price levels".
2221

23-
Such a theory of price levels was described by Thomas Sargent and Neil Wallace in chapter 5 of
24-
{cite}`sargent2013rational`, which reprints a 1981 Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis article entitled "Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic".
22+
2523

26-
Sometimes people call it a "monetary" or "monetarist" theory of price levels because fiscal effects on price levels occur through the effects of government fiscal policy decisions on the path of the money supply.
24+
Economist call it a "monetary" or "monetarist" theory of price levels because effects on price levels occur via a central banks's decisions to print money supply.
2725

2826
* a goverment's fiscal policies determine whether it **expenditures** exceed its **tax collections**
29-
* if its expenditures exceeds it tax collections, it can cover the difference by **printing money**
27+
* if its expenditures exceeds it tax collections, the government can instruct the central bank to cover the difference by **printing money**
3028
* that leads to effects on the price level as price level path adjusts to equate the supply of money to the demand for money
3129

32-
The theory has been extended, criticized, and applied by John Cochrane in {cite}`cochrane2023fiscal`.
30+
Such a theory of price levels was described by Thomas Sargent and Neil Wallace in chapter 5 of
31+
{cite}`sargent2013rational`, which reprints a 1981 Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis article entitled "Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic".
32+
33+
Sometimes this theory is also called a "fiscal theory of price levels" to emphasize the importance of fisal deficits in shaping changes in the money supply.
34+
35+
The theory has been extended, criticized, and applied by John Cochrane {cite}`cochrane2023fiscal`.
3336

3437
In another lecture {doc}`price level histories <inflation_history>`, we described some European hyperinflations that occurred in the wake of World War I.
3538

@@ -39,29 +42,29 @@ Elemental forces at work in the fiscal theory of the price level help to underst
3942
According to this theory, when the government persistently spends more than it collects in taxes and prints money to finance the shortfall (the "shortfall" is called the "government deficit"), it puts upward pressure on the price level and generates
4043
persistent inflation.
4144

42-
The "monetarist or fiscal theory of price levels" asserts that
45+
The ''monetarist'' or ''fiscal theory of price levels" asserts that
4346

44-
* to **start** a persistent inflation the government simply persistently runs a money-financed government deficit
47+
* to **start** a persistent inflation the government beings persistently to run a money-financed government deficit
4548

46-
* to **stop** a persistent inflation the government simply stops persistently running a money-financed government deficit
49+
* to **stop** a persistent inflation the government stops persistently running a money-financed government deficit
4750

48-
Our model is a "rational expectations" (or "perfect foresight") version of a model that Philip Cagan {cite}`Cagan` used to study the monetary dynamics of hyperinflations.
51+
The model in this lecture is a "rational expectations" (or "perfect foresight") version of a model that Philip Cagan {cite}`Cagan` used to study the monetary dynamics of hyperinflations.
4952

5053
While Cagan didn't use that "rational expectations" version of the model, Thomas Sargent {cite}`sargent1982ends` did when he studied the Ends of Four Big Inflations in Europe after World War I.
5154

5255
* this lecture {doc}`fiscal theory of the price level with adaptive expectations <cagan_adaptive>` describes a version of the model that does not impose "rational expectations" but instead uses
5356
what Cagan and his teacher Milton Friedman called "adaptive expectations"
5457

55-
* a reader of both lectures will notice that the algebra is easier and more streamlined in the present rational expectations version of the model
56-
* this can be traced to the following source: the adaptive expectations version of the model has more endogenous variables and more free parameters
58+
* a reader of both lectures will notice that the algebra is less complicated in the present rational expectations version of the model
59+
* the difference in algebra complications can be traced to the following source: the adaptive expectations version of the model has more endogenous variables and more free parameters
5760

58-
Some of our quantitative experiments with our rational expectations version of the model are designed to illustrate how the fiscal theory explains the abrupt end of those big inflations.
61+
Some of our quantitative experiments with the rational expectations version of the model are designed to illustrate how the fiscal theory explains the abrupt end of those big inflations.
5962

6063
In those experiments, we'll encounter an instance of a ''velocity dividend'' that has sometimes accompanied successful inflation stabilization programs.
6164

6265
To facilitate using linear matrix algebra as our main mathematical tool, we'll use a finite horizon version of the model.
6366

64-
As in the {doc}`present values <pv>` and {doc}`consumption smoothing<cons_smooth>` lectures, the only linear algebra that we'll be using are matrix multiplication and matrix inversion.
67+
As in the {doc}`present values <pv>` and {doc}`consumption smoothing<cons_smooth>` lectures, our mathematical tools are matrix multiplication and matrix inversion.
6568

6669

6770
## Structure of the model
@@ -71,7 +74,7 @@ The model consists of
7174

7275
* a function that expresses the demand for real balances of government printed money as an inverse function of the public's expected rate of inflation
7376

74-
* an exogenous sequence of rates of growth of the money supply. The money supply grows because the government is printing it to finance some of its expenditures
77+
* an exogenous sequence of rates of growth of the money supply. The money supply grows because the government prints it to pay for goods and services
7578

7679
* an equilibrium condition that equates the demand for money to the supply
7780

lectures/equalizing_difference.md

+50-35
Original file line numberDiff line numberDiff line change
@@ -18,27 +18,30 @@ kernelspec:
1818
This lecture presents a model of the college-high-school wage gap in which the
1919
"time to build" a college graduate plays a key role.
2020

21-
```{note}
22-
Milton Friedman used our model to study whether differences in the earnings of US dentists and doctors were justified by competitive labor markets or whether
23-
they reflected entry barriers imposed by US governments working in conjunction with doctors' lobbies. Chapter 4 of Jennifer Burns {cite}`Burns_2023` presents an
24-
interesting account of Milton Friedman's joint work with Simon Kuznets that eventually led to the publication of {cite}`kuznets1939incomes` and {cite}`friedman1954incomes`. To map Friedman's application to our model, think of our high school students as Friedman's dentists and our college graduates as Friedman's doctors.
25-
```
2621

27-
The model is "incomplete" in the sense that it is just one "condition" in the form of a single equation that would be part of set equations comprising all "equilibrium conditions" of a more fully articulated model.
22+
Milton Friedman invented the model to study whether differences in earnings of US dentists and doctors were outcomes of competitive labor markets or whether
23+
they reflected entry barriers imposed by governments working in conjunction with doctors' professional organizations.
24+
25+
Chapter 4 of Jennifer Burns {cite}`Burns_2023` describes Milton Friedman's joint work with Simon Kuznets that eventually led to the publication of {cite}`kuznets1939incomes` and {cite}`friedman1954incomes`.
26+
27+
To map Friedman's application into our model, think of our high school students as Friedman's dentists and our college graduates as Friedman's doctors.
28+
2829

29-
The condition featured in our model determines a college, high-school wage ratio that equalizes the present values of a high school worker and a college educated worker.
30+
Our presentation is "incomplete" in the sense that it is based on a single equation that would be part of set equilibrium conditions of a more fully articulated model.
3031

31-
The idea behind this condition is that lifetime earnings have to adjust to make someone indifferent between going to college and not going to college.
32+
This ''equalizing difference'' equation determines a college, high-school wage ratio that equalizes present values of a high school educated worker and a college educated worker.
3233

33-
(The job of the "other equations" in a more complete model would be to fill in details about what adjusts to bring about this outcome.)
34+
The idea is that lifetime earnings somehow adjust to make a new high school worker indifferent between going to college and not going to college but instead going to work immmediately.
3435

35-
It is just one instance of an "equalizing difference" theory of relative wage rates, a class of theories dating back at least to Adam Smith's **Wealth of Nations** {cite}`smith2010wealth`.
36+
(The job of the "other equations" in a more complete model would be to describe what adjusts to bring about this outcome.)
37+
38+
Our model is just one example of an "equalizing difference" theory of relative wage rates, a class of theories dating back at least to Adam Smith's **Wealth of Nations** {cite}`smith2010wealth`.
3639

3740
For most of this lecture, the only mathematical tools that we'll use are from linear algebra, in particular, matrix multiplication and matrix inversion.
3841

39-
However, at the very end of the lecture, we'll use calculus just in case readers want to see how computing partial derivatives could let us present some findings more concisely.
42+
However, near the end of the lecture, we'll use calculus just in case readers want to see how computing partial derivatives could let us present some findings more concisely.
4043

41-
(And doing that will let us show off how good Python is at doing calculus!)
44+
And doing that will let illustrate how good Python is at doing calculus!
4245

4346
But if you don't know calculus, our tools from linear algebra are certainly enough.
4447

@@ -51,15 +54,15 @@ import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
5154

5255
## The indifference condition
5356

54-
The key idea is that the initial college wage premium has to adjust to make a representative worker indifferent between going to college and not going to college.
57+
The key idea is that the entry level college wage premium has to adjust to make a representative worker indifferent between going to college and not going to college.
5558

5659
Let
5760

5861
* $R > 1$ be the gross rate of return on a one-period bond
5962

6063
* $t = 0, 1, 2, \ldots T$ denote the years that a person either works or attends college
6164

62-
* $0$ denote the first period after high school that a person can go to work
65+
* $0$ denote the first period after high school that a person can work if he does not go to college
6366

6467
* $T$ denote the last period that a person works
6568

@@ -75,7 +78,12 @@ Let
7578

7679
* $D$ be the upfront monetary costs of going to college
7780

81+
We now compute present values that a new high school graduate earns if
82+
83+
* he goes to work immediately and earns wages paid to someone without a college education
84+
* he goes to college for four years and after graduating earns wages paid to a college graduate
7885

86+
### Present value of a high school educated worker
7987

8088
If someone goes to work immediately after high school and works for the $T+1$ years $t=0, 1, 2, \ldots, T$, she earns present value
8189

@@ -91,6 +99,8 @@ $$
9199

92100
The present value $h_0$ is the "human wealth" at the beginning of time $0$ of someone who chooses not to attend college but instead to go to work immediately at the wage of a high school graduate.
93101

102+
### Present value of a college-bound new high school graduate
103+
94104

95105
If someone goes to college for the four years $t=0, 1, 2, 3$ during which she earns $0$, but then goes to work immediately after college and works for the $T-3$ years $t=4, 5, \ldots ,T$, she earns present value
96106

@@ -101,31 +111,29 @@ $$
101111
where
102112

103113
$$
104-
A_c = (R^{-1} \gamma_c)^4 \left[ \frac{1 - (R^{-1} \gamma_c)^{T-3} }{1 - R^{-1} \gamma_c } \right]
114+
A_c = (R^{-1} \gamma_c)^4 \left[ \frac{1 - (R^{-1} \gamma_c)^{T-3} }{1 - R^{-1} \gamma_c } \right] .
105115
$$
106116

107117
The present value $c_0$ is the "human wealth" at the beginning of time $0$ of someone who chooses to attend college for four years and then start to work at time $t=4$ at the wage of a college graduate.
108118

109119

110-
Assume that college tuition plus four years of room and board paid for up front costs $D$.
120+
Assume that college tuition plus four years of room and board amount to $D$ and must be paid at time $0$.
111121

112122
So net of monetary cost of college, the present value of attending college as of the first period after high school is
113123

114124
$$
115125
c_0 - D
116126
$$
117127

118-
We now formulate a pure **equalizing difference** model of the initial college-high school wage gap $\phi$ defined by
119-
120-
Let
128+
We now formulate a pure **equalizing difference** model of the initial college-high school wage gap $\phi$ that verifies
121129

122130
$$
123131
w_0^c = \phi w_0^h
124132
$$
125133

126134
We suppose that $R, \gamma_h, \gamma_c, T$ and also $w_0^h$ are fixed parameters.
127135

128-
We start by noting that the pure equalizing difference model asserts that the college-high-school wage gap $\phi$ solves
136+
We start by noting that the pure equalizing difference model asserts that the college-high-school wage gap $\phi$ solves an
129137
"equalizing" equation that sets the present value not going to college equal to the present value of going go college:
130138

131139

@@ -139,25 +147,27 @@ $$
139147
w_0^h A_h = \phi w_0^h A_c - D .
140148
$$ (eq:equalize)
141149
142-
This is the "indifference condition" that is at the heart of the model.
150+
This "indifference condition" is the heart of the model.
143151
144152
Solving equation {eq}`eq:equalize` for the college wage premium $\phi$ we obtain
145153
146154
$$
147155
\phi = \frac{A_h}{A_c} + \frac{D}{w_0^h A_c} .
148156
$$ (eq:wagepremium)
149157
150-
In a **free college** special case $D =0$ so that the only cost of going to college is the forgone earnings from not working as a high school worker.
158+
In a **free college** special case $D =0$.
159+
160+
Here the only cost of going to college is the forgone earnings from being a high school educated worker.
151161
152162
In that case,
153163
154164
$$
155165
\phi = \frac{A_h}{A_c} .
156166
$$
157167
158-
Soon we'll write Python code to compute the gap and plot it as a function of its determinants.
168+
Soon we'll write Python code to compute $\phi$ and plot it as a function of its determinants.
159169
160-
But first we'll describe a possible alternative interpretation of our model.
170+
But first we'll describe an alternative interpretation of our model that mostly just relabels variables.
161171
162172
163173
@@ -185,13 +195,18 @@ This cost might include costs of hiring workers, office space, and lawyers.
185195
What we used to call the college, high school wage gap $\phi$ now becomes the ratio
186196
of a successful entrepreneur's earnings to a worker's earnings.
187197
188-
We'll find that as $\pi$ decreases, $\phi$ increases.
198+
We'll find that as $\pi$ decreases, $\phi$ increases, indicating that the riskier it is to
199+
be an entrepreuner, the higher must be the reward for a successful project.
200+
201+
## Computations
189202
190-
Now let's write some Python code to compute $\phi$ and plot it as a function of some of its determinants.
191203
192-
We can have some fun providing some example calculations that tweak various parameters,
204+
We can have some fun with examples that tweak various parameters,
193205
prominently including $\gamma_h, \gamma_c, R$.
194206
207+
Now let's write some Python code to compute $\phi$ and plot it as a function of some of its determinants.
208+
209+
195210
```{code-cell} ipython3
196211
class equalizing_diff:
197212
"""
@@ -219,10 +234,10 @@ class equalizing_diff:
219234
```
220235
221236
237+
Using vectorization instead of loops,
238+
we build some functions to help do comparative statics .
222239
223-
We can build some functions to help do comparative statics using vectorization instead of loops.
224-
225-
For a given instance of the class, we want to compute $\phi$ when one parameter changes and others remain unchanged.
240+
For a given instance of the class, we want to recompute $\phi$ when one parameter changes and others remain fixed.
226241
227242
Let's do an example.
228243
@@ -315,7 +330,7 @@ plt.show()
315330
```
316331
Notice how the intitial wage gap falls when the rate of growth $\gamma_c$ of college wages rises.
317332
318-
It falls to "equalize" the present values of the two types of career, one as a high school worker, the other as a college worker.
333+
The wage gap falls to "equalize" the present values of the two types of career, one as a high school worker, the other as a college worker.
319334
320335
Can you guess what happens to the initial wage ratio $\phi$ when next we vary the rate of growth of high school wages, holding all other determinants of $\phi$ constant?
321336
@@ -363,9 +378,9 @@ Does the graph make sense to you?
363378
364379
So far, we have used only linear algebra and it has been a good enough tool for us to figure out how our model works.
365380
366-
However, someone who knows calculus might ask "Instead of plotting those graphs, why didn't you just take partial derivatives?"
381+
However, someone who knows calculus might want us just to take partial derivatives.
367382
368-
We'll briefly do just that, yes, the questioner is correct and that partial derivatives are indeed a good tool for discovering the "comparative statics" properities of our model.
383+
We'll do that now.
369384
370385
A reader who doesn't know calculus could read no further and feel confident that applying linear algebra has taught us the main properties of the model.
371386
@@ -433,7 +448,7 @@ Now let's compute $\frac{\partial \phi}{\partial D}$ and then evaluate it at the
433448
ϕ_D_func(D_value, γ_h_value, γ_c_value, R_value, T_value, w_h0_value)
434449
```
435450
436-
Thus, as with our graph above, we find that raising $R$ increases the initial college wage premium $\phi$.
451+
Thus, as with our earlier graph, we find that raising $R$ increases the initial college wage premium $\phi$.
437452
438453
+++
439454
@@ -469,7 +484,7 @@ Let's compute $\frac{\partial \phi}{\partial γ_h}$ and evaluate it at default p
469484
ϕ_γ_h_func(D_value, γ_h_value, γ_c_value, R_value, T_value, w_h0_value)
470485
```
471486
472-
We find that raising $\gamma_h$ increases the initial college wage premium $\phi$, as we did with our graphical analysis earlier
487+
We find that raising $\gamma_h$ increases the initial college wage premium $\phi$, as we did with our earlier graphical analysis.
473488
474489
+++
475490

0 commit comments

Comments
 (0)