You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/money_inflation_nonlinear.md
+74-53
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -45,7 +45,7 @@ That lecture will show that
45
45
* it reverses the perverse dynamics by making the *lower* stationary inflation rate the one to which the system typically converges
46
46
* a more plausible comparative dynamic outcome emerges in which now inflation can be *reduced* by running *lower* government deficits
47
47
48
-
## The model
48
+
## The Model
49
49
50
50
Let
51
51
@@ -70,56 +70,9 @@ where $g$ is the part of government expenditures financed by printing money.
70
70
71
71
**Remark:** Please notice that while equation {eq}`eq:mdemand` is linear in logs of the money supply and price level, equation {eq}`eq:msupply` is linear in levels. This will require adapting the equilibrium computation methods that we deployed in {doc}`money_inflation`.
72
72
73
-
## Computing an equilibrium sequence
74
73
75
-
We'll deploy a method similar to *Method 2* used in {doc}`money_inflation`.
76
-
77
-
We'll take the time $t$ state vector to be $m_t, p_t$.
78
-
79
-
* we'll treat $m_t$ as a ''natural state variable'' and $p_t$ as a ''jump'' variable.
80
-
81
-
Let
82
-
83
-
$$
84
-
\lambda \equiv \frac{\alpha}{1+ \alpha}
85
-
$$
86
-
87
-
Let's rewrite equation {eq}`eq:mdemand`, respectively, as
88
-
89
-
$$
90
-
p_t = (1-\lambda) m_{t+1} + \lambda p_{t+1}
91
-
$$ (eq:mdemand2)
92
-
93
-
We'll summarize our algorithm with the following pseudo-code.
* compute the inflation rate $\pi_t = p_{t+1} - p_t$ and growth of money supply $\mu_t = m_{t+1} - m_t $
104
74
105
-
* iterate on $t$ to convergence of $\pi_t \rightarrow \overline \pi$ and $\mu_t \rightarrow \overline \mu$
106
-
107
-
It will turn out that
108
-
109
-
* if they exist, limiting values $\overline \pi$ and $\overline \mu$ will be equal
110
-
111
-
* if limiting values exist, there are two possible limiting values, one high, one low
112
-
113
-
* for almost all initial log price levels $p_0$, the limiting $\overline \pi = \overline \mu$ is
114
-
the higher value
115
-
116
-
* for each of the two possible limiting values $\overline \pi$ ,there is a unique initial log price level $p_0$ that implies that $\pi_t = \mu_t = \overline \mu$ for all $t \geq 0$
117
-
118
-
* this unique initial log price level solves $\log(\exp(m_0) + g \exp(p_0)) - p_0 = - \alpha \overline \pi $
119
-
120
-
* the preceding equation for $p_0$ comes from $m_1 - p_0 = - \alpha \overline \pi$
121
-
122
-
## Limiting values of inflation rate
75
+
## Limiting Values of Inflation Rate
123
76
124
77
We can compute the two prospective limiting values for $\overline \pi$ by studying the steady-state Laffer curve.
125
78
@@ -203,7 +156,7 @@ print(f'The two steady state of π are: {π_l, π_u}')
203
156
204
157
We find two steady state $\overline \pi$ values.
205
158
206
-
## Steady state Laffer curve
159
+
## Steady State Laffer curve
207
160
208
161
The following figure plots the steady state Laffer curve together with the two stationary inflation rates.
209
162
@@ -247,9 +200,16 @@ def plot_laffer(model, πs):
247
200
plot_laffer(model, (π_l, π_u))
248
201
```
249
202
250
-
## Associated initial price levels
203
+
## Initial Price Levels
204
+
205
+
Now that we have our hands on the two possible steady states, we can compute two functions $\underline p(m_0)$ and
206
+
$\overline p(m_0)$, which as initial conditions for $p_t$ at time $t$, imply that $\pi_t = \overline \pi $ for all $t \geq 0$.
207
+
208
+
The function $\underline p(m_0)$ will be associated with $\pi_l$ the lower steady-state inflation rate.
209
+
210
+
The function $\overline p(m_0)$ will be associated with $\pi_u$ the lower steady-state inflation rate.
211
+
251
212
252
-
Now that we have our hands on the two possible steady states, we can compute two initial log price levels $p_0$, which as initial conditions, imply that $\pi_t = \overline \pi $ for all $t \geq 0$.
* compute the inflation rate $\pi_t = p_{t+1} - p_t$ and growth of money supply $\mu_t = m_{t+1} - m_t $
310
+
311
+
Next, compute the two functions $\underline p(m_0)$ and $\overline p(m_0)$ described above
312
+
313
+
Now initiate the algorithm as follows.
314
+
315
+
* set $m_0 >0$
316
+
* set a value of $p_0 \in [\underline p(m_0), \overline p(m_0)]$ and form the pair $(m_0, p_0)$ at time $t =0$
317
+
318
+
Starting from $(m_0, p_0)$ iterate on $t$ to convergence of $\pi_t \rightarrow \overline \pi$ and $\mu_t \rightarrow \overline \mu$
319
+
320
+
It will turn out that
321
+
322
+
* if they exist, limiting values $\overline \pi$ and $\overline \mu$ will be equal
323
+
324
+
* if limiting values exist, there are two possible limiting values, one high, one low
325
+
326
+
* for almost all initial log price levels $p_0$, the limiting $\overline \pi = \overline \mu$ is
327
+
the higher value
328
+
329
+
* for each of the two possible limiting values $\overline \pi$ ,there is a unique initial log price level $p_0$ that implies that $\pi_t = \mu_t = \overline \mu$ for all $t \geq 0$
330
+
331
+
* this unique initial log price level solves $\log(\exp(m_0) + g \exp(p_0)) - p_0 = - \alpha \overline \pi $
332
+
333
+
* the preceding equation for $p_0$ comes from $m_1 - p_0 = - \alpha \overline \pi$
334
+
335
+
336
+
## Slippery Side of Laffer Curve Dynamics
316
337
317
338
We are now equipped to compute time series starting from different $p_0$ settings, like those in {doc}`money_inflation`.
0 commit comments